[ View menu ]
Main

Fitness plan charges you more for working out less

Filed in Encyclopedia ,Gossip ,Ideas ,Programs
Subscribe to Decision Science News by Email (one email per week, easy unsubscribe)

ON COMMITMENT DEVICE BUSINESSES AND SOFT CONTRACTS

This week, our former home, the Center for the Decision Sciences at Columbia University, has turned us on to this article about a fitness plan that charges you more if you work out less. Yes, it’s a business putting applied behavioral economics to work, not unlike Stickk.com or Beeminder.com (formerly known as Kibotzer.com and currently known as bmndr.com by those who like to abbrvt).

The plan works in conjunction with gyms. We have often heard people say, with great assurance, that gyms bet on people not making good use of their memberships, that they are businesses based on a human inability to commit. Sure, if you take “good use” to mean going every day, it’s clear that gyms could not handle the crowds that would result. However, we at DSN often doubt people who say things with great assurance without evidence. After all, people don’t make good use of their gym memberships may not renew their memberships, and that is bad for business.

SOFT CONTRACTS: AN IDEA THAT WILL NOT WORK IN THEORY BUT WILL WORK NONETHELESS
DSN once committed to patronize the gym 150 times a year. We did pretty well for the first half of the year and then were met by a long spell of illness and travel. After that, hitting the 150 number required more frequent workouts then we cared to commit to, so we gave up. It’s a problem when commitment contracts don’t make room for periods in which you cannot, should not, or do not want to honor your contract. Yes, we grouped “do not want” with the others. For instance, suppose we had been offered an all-expense-paid, two-month trip around the world that would leave no possibility for going to the gym. Taking the once-in-a-lifetime trip would be more important to us than going to the gym 150 times per year, so we would choose to lose the gym bet to take the trip. However, that’s not ideal. What’s ideal is to honor the gym bet when we are home and healthy and to suspend it otherwise. Since we can define these preferences a priori, it should be possible to define contracts that work within those rules. However, since it is impossible to think, a priori, of every possible thing that might make one want to suspend the bet, it seems reasonable to simply trust people to be honest about when they should be honoring the contract and when not. We realize this violates all the sacred principles of commitment contracts, experimental economics, law & order, and so on, but so what. History is filled with failed token economies and successful systems of soft guidelines.

OTHER DSN POSTS ON COMMITMENT DEVICES
Stop overeating with a turn of the wrist

Contracts to fight procrastination

1 Comments

  1. Daniel Reeves says:

    I mostly agree with your idea of using the pornography test (“I’ll know it when I see it”) for determining when the contract should be suspended. Beeminder is trying to be a bit more formal about it. Here’s clause 7 of the current draft of the Beeminder contract template:

    7. SOS Clause

    If something truly unexpected happens, such as physical injury, that prevents you from staying on your yellow brick road you can make your road immediately become flat. To mitigate this otherwise abusable loophole, there are two conditions on invoking the SOS clause.

    First, you have to notify Beeminder before you officially lose. Preferably send an email to bot@beeminder.com but if you’re in the hospital or something and that’s not possible, text or, if really necessary, call 646-535-BEEM. You can also tweet to @bmndr. Or if the emergency is so severe that it’s not reasonable to notify Beeminder before you lose, you can provide a doctor’s note or death certificate or similar within 14 days.

    The second condition is that you explain in 140 characters what happened that warrants the exemption. A panel of disinterested judges will determine whether your excuse is legitimate, i.e., whether it really couldn’t have been anticipated and whether an exemption is within the spirit of this contract. The point of the 140-character limit is both to make it simple for the judges and because the excuse has to be something stark and obvious like “I broke my leg”, not some kind of convoluted confluence of craziness at work and bad luck. An excuse at all resembling “I got really busy” won’t fly.

    The litmus test for whether an excuse is legitimate is “Had I considered the possibility of the Unexpected Thing happening, would I have specified an exemption in the original contract?”

    February 15, 2011 @ 12:19 pm

RSS feed Comments

Write Comment

XHTML: <a href="" title=""> <abbr title=""> <acronym title=""> <b> <blockquote cite=""> <cite> <code> <del datetime=""> <em> <i> <q cite=""> <s> <strike> <strong>